Teaching Notes With Suggested Answers

The Excel Workbook Answers to Part 1.1 are in the exam02a.xls file at http://www.cs.trinity.edu/~rjensen/Exams/5341sp02/exam02/

 

ACCT 5341 Examination 2


Part 1

Dr. Jensen

Spring 2002

 

Students may use any reference materials available in the Trinity Library and on the Web.

 

Students may not obtain help from any person other than Dr. Jensen.  His help is limited to clarification questions regarding what is required for a given question or problem.

Part 1 ESO Tax Benefits

The starting point for Part 1 is Appendix A of a letter written by Professor Jensen to Senator Charles E. Schumer.  An Appendix C has been added to Professor Jensen’s original letter, and the letter has not yet been mailed.  The purpose of Part 1 of this examination is to compare how you would write an Appendix C that addresses the tax benefit controversy of employee stock options (ESOs).  The letter of Walter Schuetze to Senator Schumer,  The primary documents useful to this examination are as follows:

1.      “Accounting for Tax Benefits of Employee Stock Options and Implications for Research,” Accounting Horizons, Vo. 16, No. 1, March 2002, pp. 1-16.

2.      Chapter 11 of Business Analysis & Valuation, by K.G. Palepu, P.m. Healy, and V.I. Bernard (South-Western Publishing, 2000, ISBN 0-324-02002-3).

3.      FAS 123 entitled “Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation.”  This standard is available from the Financial Accounting Standards Board at http://accounting.rutgers.edu/raw/fasb/
Trinity University students may find the document on the path
J:\courses\acct5341\ExamHints\Fas123

4.      On March 25, 2002, Walter P. Schuetze, former Chief Accountant of the Securities and Exchange Commission, wrote Senator Schumer a letter that leaves no doubt that he opposes booking of employee stock options when they vest. That letter is now on the Web at http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/schuetze01.htm

5.      Bob Jensen’s reply that points out some opposing arguments. The initial reply is on the Web at http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Initially, the above document contains an incomplete Appendix C that is Part 1 of this examination.  You are prepare an answer key for this examination.  That key will complete the Appendix C.

Required:

1.      You are to fill in the cells that have been blanked out below.  Please enter your results in the Excel spreadsheet that accompanies this examination.  That spreadsheet can be downloaded from the exam02q.xls file on the path http://www.cs.trinity.edu/~rjensen/Exams/5341sp02/exam02/
Warning:  Since you will be asked what happens when the tax rate varies, it is best to derive your spreadsheet answers in such a way that you can easily derive different outcomes with each change in the tax rate.

2.      A copy of Hanlon and Shevlon (2002) cited above is provided in this examination.  You are to use this paper for guidance in completing the spreadsheet required above. 

3.      Fill in all the table blanks and answer the questions on the following pages.  Assume that ESO tax benefits arise only when stock options are exercised.  Initially assume that the options in Appendix C can only be exercised at the end of Year 5.

4.      When you are asked to value these companies at the beginning of Year 1, pretend that the revenue and expense cash flows are estimates.  For guidance on the valuation calculations, to the Excel workbook on the path J:\courses\acct5341\ExamHints\FAS123\Appendices.xls

 


Part 1.1 (40 Points)
Fill in the blanks below after filling in the yellow cells of the Part 1 spreadsheet in the Exam3q.xls file.  The accounting is to proceed according to APB 25 procedures (see Hanlon and Shevlon (2002)).

Grading Note:  Half the points on Part 1 depended upon the correct accounting for the exercise of the stock options under APB 25 at the end of Year 5.  In particular, note the top of Page 3 in Hanlon and Shevlon (2002).

The Excel Workbook Answers to Part 1.1 are in the exam02a.xls file at http://www.cs.trinity.edu/~rjensen/Exams/5341sp02/exam02/

 

Year 5 After Exercise of Options

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

Operating  revenue

$320,000

$320,000

Interest revenue

$12,367

$23,424

Labor expense

$160,000

$0

Net profit before income tax (NBOT)

$172,367

$343,424

Income tax expense

$51,710

$103,027

Net profit

$120,657

$240,397

Cash

$244,329

$727,659

Capital

($10,000)

($263,027)

Retained earnings

($234,329)

($464,632)

Number of shares

10,000

25,000

Earnings Per Share

$12.07

$9.62

Value of options before exercised

$0

$500,000

Value of options after exercised

 

$0

Book Value Per Share

$24.43

$29.11

 

 

 

 

 

Nobel Option Reconciliation of Cash in Year 5

Appendix A Cash without interest and taxes =

$780,000

Interest revenue =

$43,760

Less Income Taxes Payable paid in cash =

($96,101)

Appendix C Cash With Taxes =

$727,659

 

 

 

Nobel Option Reconciliation of Capital in Year 5

Appendix A Capital without taxes =

($160,000)

Additional paid-in capital from ESO tax benefit =

($103,027)

Appendix C Capital With Taxes =

($263,027)

 

 

 

Nobel Option Reconciliation of Retained Earnings in Yr 5

Appendix A Retained Earnings without interest and taxes =

($620,000)

Interest revenue =

($43,760)

Less Income Tax Expense in financial statements =

$199,128

Appendix C Retained Earnings With Taxes =

($464,632)

 

 

 

 

Initial Investment and Net Profits

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

0

$7,700

$10,000

1

$7,700

$14,700

2

$15,239

$29,729

3

$30,306

$59,810

4

$60,427

$119,997

5

$120,657

$240,397

NPV =

$166,254

$324,096

Cost of Capital =

10.00%

10.00%

Dividend Cash Flow Valuation

$151,709

$451,819

Residual Income Model Valuation

$151,709

$387,847

FCF Flow Valuation

$151,709

$451,819

 

 

 

Dividend Cash Flow Valuation

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

Cost of Capital =

10.0000%

10.0000%

Year t

Dividend Cash Flows

Dividend Cash Flows

1

$0

$0

2

$0

$0

3

$0

$0

4

$0

$0

5

$244,329

$577,659

ESO New Equity Investment in Year 5 =

$0

$150,000

Dividend Est. Value of Firm at Time 0

$151,709

$451,819

Dividend Est. Value Per Share at Time 0

$15.17

$18.07

 

 

 

 

 

 

Residual Income Valuation

 

 

 

 

 

Residual Income Valuation

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

Cost of Capital = r =

10.00%

10.00%

Year t

Book Value (0)

Book Value (0)

0

$10,000

$10,000

 

Net Profit (t)-(r)(Book Value (t-1))

Net Profit (t)-(r)(Book Value (t-1))

1

$6,700

$13,700

2

$13,469

$27,259

3

$27,012

$54,367

4

$54,103

$108,573

5

$108,290

$216,973

ESO New Equity Investment in Year 5 =

$0

$150,000

RI Estimated Value of Firm at Time 0

$151,709

$387,847

RI Est. Value Per Share at Time 0

$15.17

$15.51

 

 

 

 

 

 

Free Cash Flow Valuation

 

 

 

 

 

Free Cash Flow Valuation

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

Cost of Capital =

10.0000%

10.0000%

Year t

FCF(t)

FCF(t)

1

$0

$0

2

$0

$0

3

$0

$0

4

$0

$0

5

$244,329

$577,659

ESO New Equity Investment in Year 5 =

$0

$150,000

FCF Estimated Value of Firm at Time 0

$151,709

$451,819

FCF Est. Value Per Share at Time 0

$15.17

$18.07

 


Part 1.2 (10 Points)  Abnormal Earnings Valuation

When comparing the Dividends versus Abnormal Earnings/Residual Income valuation outcomes, note that these outcomes are identical ($151,709) for the Nobel Cash Company.  They are not identical for the Nobel Option Company.  What is this difference and how do you account for the difference.  Why is that the case, and what is a fundamental problem with Abnormal Earnings/Residual Income Model valuation?

Hint:  Carefully read the introduction to the Abnormal Earnings Valuation Method introduction on Page 11-3 of Business Analysis & Valuation, by K.G. Palepu, P.m. Healy, and V.I. Bernard (South-Western Publishing, 2000, ISBN 0-324-02002-3).  Especially note the underlying assumption and Footnote 1 on Page 11-22..  What are some of the reasons analysts still prefer the Abnormal Earnings Valuation model?

Suggested Answer:

 

Nobel Cash Company

Nobel Option Company

Dividend Cash Flow Valuation

$151,709

$451,819

Residual Income Model Valuation

$151,709

$387,847

Valuation Difference

$0

$63,972

The valuations are estimated at the beginning of Year 1.  If we compute the future value of the $63,972 valuation difference five years out using the Nobel Option's cost of capital rate of 10.00%, that future value is $103,027, which is exactly equal to the ESO tax benefit.  Or put in another way, the valuation difference of $63,972 is the present value (at Time 0) of the ESO tax benefit of $103,027 at the end of Year 5.

The reason for the $63,972 lower valuation from the Residual Income/Abnormal Earnings Model, is that this valuation model assumes a "clean surplus" in which all equity capital changes other than new share issuances pass through earnings.  Under APB 25, the ESO tax benefit arising from the intrinsic value of exercised stock options gives rise in this illustration to a $103,027 tax benefit that wiped out all taxes payable for the Nobel Option Company in Year 5.  The APB 25 required entry for this is a debit to Cash (or Taxes Payable) and a credit to Capital (or Paid-in Capital).  As a result, Nobel Option Company does not satisfy the required assumption of a "clean surplus" in Year 5 due to the fact that the $103,027 did not increase earnings but did increase Capital.

The $150,000 received from the issuance of new shares is not a cause of any valuation model difference since this does not violate the clean surplus assumption.

 


Part 1.3 Market Value at the End of Year 4

Part A (5 Points)
What are the book values per share at the end of Year 4? 

$12.37 in the Nobel Cash Company

$23.42 in the Nobel Option Company

Part B (10 Points)
The book value in both companies at the end of Year 4 maps to the only asset of each company --- Cash.  If each company went public with an IPO at the end of Year 4, what factors might make the market value of a Nobel Cash Company’s share of stock worth more than the market value of Nobel Option Company?  When answering this question, ignore any possible differences in off-balance sheet items other than ESOs.  Also assume that at the end of Year 4, it is not known that the firm will liquidate in Year 5.

Suggested Answer:

Astute investors may see the Nobel Option Company ESO obligations lying in wait.  Although Nobel Option Company has higher earnings performance, higher book value, and more cash, all of these items are completely due to the fact that in this example, Nobel Option Company had lower wages. 

Before they are exercised, the ESOs are off-balance sheet claims to the assets of the company.  They have lower priority than creditor claims, and they are contingency claims in the sense that they must have intrinsic value at the time they are exercised.  Intrinsic value is equal to the option value minus strike price.  If intrinsic value of ESOs exists, there is a dilution impact that will lower the book value and market value per share if a significant number of such options are exercised.

 

Part C (10 Points)
The book value in both companies at the end of Year 4 maps to the only asset of each company --- Cash.  If each company went public with an IPO at the end of Year 4, what factors might make the market value of a Nobel Cash Company’s share of stock worth less than the market value of Nobel Option Company?  When answering this question, ignore any possible differences in off-balance sheet items other than ESOs.  Also assume that at the end of Year 4, it is not known that the firm will liquidate in Year 5.

Suggested Answer:

The first reason can be a real economic reason.  When employees, such as in the Nobel Option Company, take ESOs in lieu of higher wages, the company has more cash and lower labor expense under APB 25 accounting.  If that cash is invested in the future for returns higher than the firm’s cost of capital, investors should give higher value to the added earnings. 

In some sense, the outcome described above acts like an interest-free loan from employees to the company.  They eventually want some type of cash return on their ESOs, but they are willing to forego cash now for later returns.

The second reason is that investors may not be as astute as assumed in Part B above.  Investors may not see the Nobel Option Company ESO obligations lying in wait.  Or they may see them, but may not be aware of the full potential of the dilution impacts.

 

Part D (10 Points)
The book value in both companies at the end of Year 4 maps to the only asset of each company --- Cash.  Could the market value of a Nobel Option Company’s share of stock worth less than the company’s book value at the end of Year 4?  When answering this question, ignore any possible differences in off-balance sheet items other than ESOs.  Also assume that at the end of Year 4, it is not known that the firm will liquidate in Year 5

Suggested Answer:

It is somewhat confusing if investors value each share less than the cash they would receive if the firm is liquidated.  However, if the firm is not being liquidated, investors anticipate future earnings and cash flows.  Their outlook for the future may assign a higher or lower value vis-à-vis current exit value.

There are many types of intangibles, contingent liabilities, and other factors that make book value of dubious importance when estimating market value.

Robert K. Elliott
Challenge and Achievement in Accounting During the Twentieth Century
, edited by Daniel L. Jensen (The Ohio State University and the University of Florida's Fisher College of Business, 2002, pp. 22-23)

MR. ELLIOTT:

If I could just respond to one point.  No one says that GAAP isn't important or that it doesn't give important information about value realization.  But in the marketplace there's an increasing gap between value creation, about which we have no good models, and value realization, the later realization of the value that's created.  If we look back to the Industrial Era, the gap between when value was created and when it was realized wasn't so  great, and we could live with it.  But now there is a huge gap, and we never claimed as accountants that the net worth on the balance sheet was supposed to equal the value of the company.  But 10 or 20 years ago, the ratio of market value to book value was about 2 to 1.  Today it's about 6 to 1.  And for some companies over 100 to 1.  What that tells us, I think, is that what's measured in the balance sheet is seriously lagging what's happening in the marketplace.  Yes, we have to be concerned with value realization.  In the end we have to make profits and have cash.   But our GAAP measures are really not diagnostic for investors to figure out which companies are actually creating value.  In the absence of disciplined information about those areas, assured information about those areas, the marketplace runs on rumors.  Those rumors tend to be wrong and that expresses itself in the marketplace in terms of huge volatility.  That volatility then leads to higher cost of capital, as investors demand to be compensated for that volatility.

Now, I'm not recommending that these assets necessarily be reduced to debits and credits and put on the balance sheet.  I'm not talking about the necessity to incorporate them all into the existing GAAP model.  What I am saying is that there is objective information that could be developed about these things, that this could be done in a way that's similar across enterprises in the same industry, and that assurance could be given about such information which would make the market estimates in value creation better than they are today.  Perfect?  No.  I'm not looking for perfection.  I'm looking for better than today.


Part 1.4 (10 Points) ESO Tax Benefits

How can current APB 25 rules adjusting for the ESO tax benefits lead to misleading conclusions by analysts about how much management is managing earnings through the use of its discretionary changes in the FAS 109 valuation allowance?

Hint:  See the bottom of Page 7 in the Hanlon and Shevlon (2002) paper.

Suggested Answer:

Firms are obligated by FAS 109 to provide a valuation allowance when any part of the deferred tax asset is not likely to be realized.  Adjustments to this valuation allowance flow through income tax expense and affect income on an after-tax basis.  Tests searching for evidence of earnings management often view manipulation of the valuation allowance as a prime suspect.  But when some part of th evaluation allowance change flows directly to shareholders’ equity, bypassing income tax expense, the tests may signal unwarranted conclusions.

Studies by Miller and Skinner (1998) and Visvanathan (1998) conclude that changes in this valuation allowance, after controlling for known economic determinants of its balance, do not signal earnings management.  Both these sutides mignt have concluded differently had the ESO tax benefits associated with the valuation allowance changes been properly treated.  See Hanlon and Shevlon (2002, Page 8)

 

 


Part 1. 5  ESO Expense Recognition

Paragraph 74 of FAS 123 reads as follows.

Paragraphs 75-117 of this (FAS 123) appendix discuss the reasons for the Board's principal conclusions on recognition and measurement issues, which support the Board's belief that recognition of stock-based employee compensation cost determined according to the fair value based method is preferable to continued application of Opinion 25 with only pro forma disclosures of the effect of recognizing stock-based employee compensation cost. That discussion begins with the basic issue of why employee stock options give rise to recognizable compensation cost.

Part A (10 Points)
In your own words, briefly summarize in less than 400 words, the arguments for the FASB conclusions in Paragraph 74 above.  Only the first 400 words will be graded.

I think the main argument against APB 45 accounting in which continues to allow firms not to book ESOs can be found in the following paragraph from FAS 123:

85. Some people told the Board that a requirement to recognize compensation cost might bring additional discipline to the use of employee stock options. Unless and until the stock price rises sufficiently to result in a dilutive effect on earnings per share, the current accounting for most fixed stock options treats them as though they were a "free good." Stock options have value--employee stock options are granted as consideration for services and thus are not free.

There are many other arguments for booking of ESOS that are discussed below.

There is a terrible inconsistency between tax law and APB 25 accounting rules for ESOs.  APB 25 allows firms to never book ESO intrinsic value given to employees including intrinsic value on the date they are exercised.  The tax code says that employees receive intrinsic value and allows companies to charge this intrinsic value to reduce taxes payable.  Firms get huge permanent tax benefits for things of value given to employees that are never recognized assets being given up by the firms.  The amounts involved are not trivial.

Many large corporations tend to avoid virtually all taxation.  For example, employee stock options allow enormous permanent reductions in corporate taxes for benefits that will never cost the corporation anything in terms of corporate assets.  Michele Hanlon and Terry Shevlon, Accounting Horizons, March 2002, Page 2 state the following:

A recent article in the Wall Street Journal (August 4, 2002, Page A2) "Cisco, Microsoft, Get Income Tax Break on Gains from Employee Stock Options" reports that for its fiscal year ended July 29, 2000, Cisco received a Tax benefit of nearly $2.5 billion dollars from the exercise of employees' stock options (ESOs).  As a result, the company paid little or no federal income taxes while reporting $2.67 billion in profits. 

The arguments for booking of all employee stock options and counter arguments against the critics are summarized very well in Appendix A of FAS 123.  Several of the most important paragraphs are quoted below.

Excerpts from FAS 123 Appendix A
BASIS FOR CONCLUSIONS

 

56. Accounting for stock-based employee compensation plans is a pervasive subject that affects most public entities and many nonpublic entities. Opinion 25 continues to be criticized for producing anomalous results and for lacking an underlying conceptual rationale that helps in resolving implementation questions or in deciding how to account for stock-based compensation plans with new features. A frequently cited anomaly is that the requirements of Opinion 25 typically result in the recognition of compensation cost for performance options but no cost is recognized for fixed options that may be more valuable at the grant date than performance options. Critics of Opinion 25 also note that long-term fixed options granted to employees are valuable financial instruments, even though they carry restrictions that usually are not present in other stock options. Financial statements prepared in accordance with the requirements of Opinion 25 do not recognize that value. The resulting financial statements are less credible than they could be, and the financial statements of entities that use fixed employee options extensively are not comparable to those of entities that do not make significant use of fixed options. Because of the various criticisms of Opinion 25, in March 1984, the Board added a project to its agenda to reconsider accounting by employers for stock-based compensation plans.

Why the Board Decided Not to Require Fair Value Accounting

59. Unlike other highly controversial topics, the controversy on accounting for stock-based compensation escalated throughout the exposure process. The main point of contention was whether compensation cost should be recognized for stock options with fixed terms that are at-the-money \13/ at the date they are granted. Constituents gave different reasons for opposing cost recognition, with many expressing concerns about whether the fair value of employee stock options at the grant date can be estimated with sufficient reliability. Most respondents urged the Board to expand disclosures about stock-based employee compensation arrangements rather than to change the basic accounting method in Opinion 25. The specific comments of respondents to the Exposure Draft and later comments made as the Board redeliberated the issues are discussed later in this appendix.

===========================================================================
 \13/ For convenience, this appendix uses the terms at-the-money, out-of-the-money, and in-the-money commonly used by option traders to denote an option with an exercise price that equals, exceeds, or is less than, respectively, the current price of the underlying stock. ===========================================================================

60. The debate on accounting for stock-based compensation unfortunately became so divisive that it threatened the Board's future working relationship with some of its constituents. Eventually, the nature of the debate threatened the future of accounting standards setting in the private sector.

61. The Board continues to believe that financial statements would be more relevant and representationally faithful if the estimated fair value of employee stock options was included in determining an entity's net income, just as all other forms of compensation are included. To do so would be consistent with accounting for the cost of all other goods and services received as consideration for equity instruments. The Board also believes that financial reporting would be improved if all equity instruments granted to employees, including instruments with variable features such as options with performance criteria for vesting, were accounted for on a consistent basis. However, in December 1994, the Board decided that the extent of improvement in financial reporting that was envisioned when this project was added to its technical agenda and when the Exposure Draft was issued was not attainable because the deliberate, logical consideration of issues that usually leads to improvement in financial reporting was no longer present. Therefore, the Board decided to specify as preferable and to encourage but not to require recognition of compensation cost for all stock-based employee compensation, with required disclosure of the pro forma effects of such recognition by entities that continue to apply Opinion 25.

 

Why Stock-Based Employee Compensation Is a Cost That Should Be Recognized in Financial Statements

74. Paragraphs 75-117 of this appendix discuss the reasons for the Board's principal conclusions on recognition and measurement issues, which support the Board's belief that recognition of stock-based employee compensation cost determined according to the fair value based method is preferable to continued application of Opinion 25 with only pro forma disclosures of the effect of recognizing stock-based employee compensation cost. That discussion begins with the basic issue of why employee stock options give rise to recognizable compensation cost.

75. The Board's conclusion that recognizing the costs of all stock-based employee compensation, including fixed, at-the-money stock options, is the preferable accounting method stems from the following premises:

a. Employee stock options have value.

b. Valuable financial instruments given to employees give rise to compensation cost that is properly included in measuring an entity's net income.

c. The value of employee stock options can be estimated within acceptable limits for recognition in financial statements.

Employee Stock Options Have Value

76. An option or warrant to buy an entity's stock for a fixed price during an extended future time period is a valuable right, even if the ways in which the holder can exercise the right are limited. Investors pay cash to buy stock options and warrants that generally have fewer restrictions than employee stock options, and unrestricted options and warrants are traded daily in financial markets. The additional restrictions inherent in employee stock options, such as the inability to transfer the option to a third party for cash, cause the value of an employee stock option to be less than the value of an otherwise identical tradable option at any time before the expiration date, but the restrictions do not render employee stock options valueless.

77. Employees rarely pay cash to acquire their employee stock options. Instead, employees provide services to their employer in exchange for cash, stock options, and other employee benefits. Even if employees are required to pay a nominal amount of cash for their options, it usually is far less than the fair value of the options received. The majority of the consideration an employer receives for employee stock options is employee services. Nonrecognition of compensation cost implies either that employee stock options are free to employees or that the options have no value--neither of which is true.

78. Some respondents argued that an employee stock option has value only if the employee ultimately realizes a gain from it. The Board does not agree. Many traded options ultimately expire worthless; that does not mean that the options had no value either when they were written or at any other time before they expired. An employee stock option has value when it is granted regardless of whether, ultimately, (a) the employee exercises the option and purchases stock worth more than the employee pays for it or (b) the option expires worthless at the end of the option period. The grant date value of a stock option is the value at that date of the right to purchase an entity's stock at a fixed price for an extended time period. Investors pay cash to acquire that right--employees provide services to acquire it.

Valuable Financial Instruments Given to Employees Give Rise to Compensation Cost That Is Properly Included in Measuring an Entity's Net Income

79. Employees provide services for which employers pay compensation. The components of an employee's total compensation package are, to some extent, flexible. The compensation package, for example, might include more cash and less health insurance, or the package might include stock options and less cash. Some employers even offer employees a choice between predetermined amounts of cash and stock options.

80. Large employers have included stock options in the compensation packages of upper echelon management for many years, and some employers recently have adopted broad-based plans that cover most of their full-time employees. A stated objective of issuing stock options is to align employee interests with those of shareholders and thereby motivate employees to work to maximize shareholder value. In addition, many start-up and other cash-poor entities provide stock options to make up for cash wages and other benefits that are less than those available elsewhere. Many respondents from younger, rapidly growing entities said that their success was attributable in large part to their extensive use of stock options; without stock options, they could not have attracted and retained the employees they needed.

81. Some respondents said that stock options are not direct compensation for services rendered and thus are not comparable to cash salaries and wages. Rather, stock options usually have other objectives, such as to attract valuable employees and to encourage them to stay with the employer by requiring a period of service before their options vest and become exercisable. Stock options, like other forms of incentive compensation, also are intended to motivate employees to perform better than they might have without the incentive. Stock-based compensation awards often are intended to compensate employees for incremental efforts beyond the basic performance required to earn their salaries or wages. Respondents that made those points generally said that the value of stock options is not a compensation cost that should be recognized in the entity's financial statements.

82. The Board acknowledges that employee stock options, as well as other forms of stock-based compensation, usually are not direct substitutes for a stated amount of cash salaries. That does not, however, imply that the value of options issued to employees is not a recognizable cost. Group medical and life insurance, disability insurance, employer-paid memberships in health clubs, and the like also are not direct compensation like cash salaries because the amount of benefit that an individual employee may receive does not necessarily vary directly with either the amount or the quality of the services rendered. However, virtually everyone agrees that the costs of those benefits are properly deducted in determining the entity's net income. Like employee stock options, benefits such as medical insurance and pensions are compensation in the broad sense of costs incurred to attract, retain, and motivate employees. It has long been an established practice that, even if employee benefits are paid--directly or indirectly--with shares of the employer's stock, the value of the stock issued to the employee or the service provider is a cost to be reported in the employer's income statement.

83. Some opponents of recognizing compensation cost for stock options acknowledge that stock options are recognizable compensation, but they say that a requirement to recognize that compensation would have adverse economic consequences because many entities would reduce or eliminate their stock option programs. However, some of the same respondents also said that Opinion 25's bias in favor of fixed awards at the expense of awards with performance conditions, options with indexed exercise prices, and the like should be eliminated because that bias has undesirable economic consequences. It deters employers from using more performance-based awards, which those respondents consider preferable to fixed options in many situations.

84. The Board's operating precepts require it to consider issues in an even-handed manner, without intentionally attempting to encourage or to discourage specific economic actions. That does not imply that improved financial reporting should not have economic consequences; a change in accounting standards that makes available more relevant and representationally faithful financial information often will have economic consequences. For example, the availability of the new information resulting from application of this Statement may lead an entity to reassess the costs and benefits of its existing stock option plans. If a reassessment reveals that the expected benefits of a stock option plan do not justify its costs, a rational response would be to revise or eliminate the plan. However, an entity presumably would not restrict or eliminate a stock option program whose motivational effect on employees is expected to make a net contribution to reported results of operations. To do so would not be rational because continuing the plan would be expected to increase revenues (or to decrease other expenses) more than enough to offset the reported compensation cost. In addition, many small, emerging entities told the Board that stock options often substitute for higher cash wages or other benefits, such as pensions. Significantly reducing those option programs would not make economic sense if employees would demand equal or greater cash wages or other benefits to replace the lost stock options.

85. Some people told the Board that a requirement to recognize compensation cost might bring additional discipline to the use of employee stock options. Unless and until the stock price rises sufficiently to result in a dilutive effect on earnings per share, the current accounting for most fixed stock options treats them as though they were a "free good." Stock options have value--employee stock options are granted as consideration for services and thus are not free.

86. Some respondents said that recognizing the compensation cost stemming from stock options would, by itself, raise the cost of capital of all entities that use options extensively. An individual entity's cost of capital would rise only if its lenders or buyers and sellers of its stock had previously been misled by the accounting under Opinion 25 to believe that fixed, at-the-money employee stock options have no value and thus impose no cost on the entity. If that were the situation for an individual entity or a group of entities, any increase in cost of capital would result from new, relevant information. Making available at an acceptable cost information that is helpful in making investment, credit, and similar decisions is the overriding objective of financial reporting.

87. Some respondents that agreed with the Board's conclusion that accounting standards, by themselves, are highly unlikely to have negative economic consequences noted that the market abhors uncertainty. Reducing uncertainty can reduce the cost of capital. Therefore, recognizing in financial statements the cost of all stock-based compensation measured in a reasonable and internally consistent manner might lower rather than raise an entity's cost of capital. Financial statement users no longer would have to decide how to consider the cost of stock options in their analysis of an entity, knowing that whatever method they chose would be based on inadequate information. With amounts recognized and measured on a reasonable and consistent basis that takes into account detailed information generally available only to the entity, users might still choose to modify or use the available information in different ways, but they would have a reasonable starting point for their analysis.

Expenses and Capital Transactions

88. Some respondents pointed out that the definition of expenses in FASB Concepts Statement No. 6, Elements of Financial Statements, says that expenses result from outflows or using up of assets or incurring of liabilities (or both). They asserted that because the issuance of stock options does not result in the incurrence of a liability, no expense should be recognized. The Board agrees that employee stock options are not a liability--like stock purchase warrants, employee stock options are equity instruments of the issuer. However, equity instruments, including employee stock options, are valuable financial instruments and thus are issued for valuable consideration, which often is cash or other financial instruments but for employee stock options is employee services. Using in the entity's operations the benefits embodied in the asset received results in an expense, regardless of whether the consideration is cash or other financial instruments, goods, or services. \14/ Moreover, even if shares of stock or other equity instruments are donated to a charity, the fair value of the instruments issued is recognized together with other charitable contributions in determining the issuer's net income. The Board recently reaffirmed that general principle in FASB Statement No. 116, Accounting for Contributions Received and Contributions Made.

===========================================================================
\14/ Concepts Statement 6, paragraph 81, ñfootnote 43, notes that, in concept, most expenses decrease assets. However, if receipt of an asset, such as services, and its use occur virtually simultaneously, the asset often is not recorded. ===========================================================================

89. Others noted that the issuance of an employee stock option is a capital transaction. They contended that capital transactions do not give rise to expenses. As discussed in paragraph 88, however, issuances of equity instruments result in the receipt of cash, other financial instruments, goods, or services, which give rise to expenses as they are used in an entity's operations. Accounting for the consideration received for issuing equity instruments has long been fundamental to the accounting for all free-standing equity instruments except one--fixed stock options subject to the requirements of Opinion 25.

90. Some respondents also asserted that the issuance of an employee stock option is a transaction directly between the recipient and the preexisting stockholders in which the stockholders agree to share future equity appreciation with employees. The Board disagrees. Employees provide services to the entity--not directly to the individual stockholders--as consideration for their options. Carried to its logical conclusion, that view would imply that the issuance of virtually any equity instrument, at least those issued for goods or services rather than cash or other financial instruments, should not affect the issuer's financial statements. For example, no asset or related cost would be reported if shares of stock were issued to acquire legal or consulting services, tangible assets, or an entire business in a business combination. Moreover, in practice today, even if a stockholder directly pays part of an employee's cash compensation (or other corporate expenses), the transaction and the related costs are reflected in the entity's financial statements, together with the stockholder's contribution to paid-in capital. To omit such costs would give a misleading picture of the entity's financial performance.

91. The Board sees no conceptual basis that justifies different accounting for the issuance of employee stock options than for all other transactions involving either equity instruments or employee services. As explained in paragraphs 57-62, the Board's decision not to require recognition of compensation expense based on the fair value of options issued to employees was not based on conceptual considerations.

Prepaid Compensation

92. The Exposure Draft proposed that an asset, prepaid compensation, be recognized at the date stock-based employee compensation awards are granted; the prepaid compensation would represent the value already conveyed to employees for services to be received in the future. Later, compensation cost would have been incurred as the benefits embodied in that asset were used up; that is, as the employees rendered service during the vesting period.

93. Many respondents objected to the recognition of prepaid compensation at the grant date. They said that, unlike most other amounts paid to suppliers before services are received, the proposed prepaid compensation for nonvested stock-based employee compensation did not meet the definition of an asset in ñparagraph 25 of Concepts Statement 6, which defines assets as "probable future economic benefits obtained or controlled by a particular entity as a result of past transactions or events" (footnote reference omitted). Prepaid fees for legal services, consulting services, insurance services, and the like represent probable future economic benefits that are controlled by the entity because the other party to the transaction has entered into a contract to provide services to earn the fees. The service provider is not entitled to walk away from its obligation to render the services that are the subject of the contract by merely foregoing collection of the fee for services not rendered. Although courts rarely enforce specific performance under a service contract, a construction contractor, for example, cannot decide unilaterally not to finish a building after digging the foundation without being subject to legal action for monetary damages by the other party to the contract. Contracts sometimes specify the damages to be paid if the contract is broken. In other circumstances, such as prepaid rent or insurance, the purchaser of the service may be able to successfully sue for specific performance--the right to occupy an office or to be reimbursed for fire damage, for example.

94. Those respondents said that employee stock options do not represent probable future benefits that are controlled by the employer at the date the options are granted because employees are not obligated to render the services required to earn their options. The contract is unilateral--not bilateral--because the entity has only conditionally transferred forfeitable equity instruments and is obligated to issue the instruments if and when the employee has rendered the specified service or satisfied other conditions. However, the employee is not obligated to perform the services and may leave the employer's service without being subject to damages beyond the loss of the compensation that would have been paid had the services been rendered.

95. The Board agreed that an entity does not obtain an asset for future service to be rendered at the date employee stock options are granted. Therefore, this Statement does not require recognition of prepaid compensation at the grant date. Rather, the cost of the related services is accrued and charged to compensation cost only in the period or periods in which the related services are received. At the grant date, awards of stock-based employee compensation are fully executory contracts. Once employees begin to render the services necessary to earn the compensation, execution of the contracts has begun, and recognition of the services already received is appropriate. The Board's conclusions on how to attribute compensation cost to the periods in which the entity receives the related employee services are discussed further in paragraphs 196-203.

96. An equity instrument may be conditionally transferred to another party under an agreement that allows that party to choose at a later date whether to deliver the agreed consideration for it, which may be goods or services rather than cash or financial instruments, or to forfeit the right to the instrument conditionally transferred, with no further obligation. In that situation, the equity instrument is not issued for accounting purposes until the issuing entity has received consideration for it and the condition is thus satisfied. The grant of an employee stock option subject to vesting conditions is an example of such a conditional transfer. For that reason, this Statement does not use the term issued to refer to the grant of a stock option or other equity instrument that is subject to service or performance conditions for vesting. The Board's conclusion that the entity receives no asset at the date employee stock options are granted is consistent with that use of the term issued. That conclusion about the issuance date of employee stock options, in turn, has implications for the appropriate date at which to measure the value of the equity instruments issued. This Statement requires a measurement method that combines attributes of both grant date and vesting date measurement. The Board's conclusions on measurement date and method are discussed in paragraphs 149-154.

 

Disclosure Is Not a Substitute for Recognition

102. FASB Concepts Statement No. 5, Recognition and Measurement in Financial Statements of Business Enterprises, says:

Since recognition means depiction of an item in both words and numbers, with the amount included in the totals of the financial statements, disclosure by other means is not recognition. Disclosure of information about the items in financial statements and their measures that may be provided by notes or parenthetically on the face of financial statements, by supplementary information, or by other means of financial reporting is not a substitute for recognition in financial statements for items that meet recognition criteria. [paragraph 9]

103. Many respondents contended that improved disclosures about employee stock options in the notes to financial statements would be as useful as recognition of compensation cost in the income statement. A specific disclosure proposal submitted by a group of providers and users of financial statements and endorsed by the largest accounting firms was illustrated in Appendix E of the Exposure Draft. Most respondents, including some that had previously endorsed that proposal, agreed that the proposed disclosures were too extensive and included some items that more properly belong in a proxy statement. The Board received several other proposals for disclosures in lieu of recognition during the exposure period and during its redeliberations of the conclusions in the Exposure Draft. Some of those proposals included a measure of the value of options granted during the year, but most focused largely on greatly expanding the detailed data disclosed about stock-based employee compensation plans.

104. As discussed in paragraphs 57-62, the Board's decision to encourage but not to require recognition of compensation cost for the fair value of stock-based employee compensation was not based on acceptance of the view that disclosure is an adequate substitute for recognition in the financial statements. If disclosure and recognition were equal alternatives, the arguments for only disclosing either detailed information about stock-based employee compensation awards or the amount of unrecognized cost would apply equally to other costs such as depreciation, warranties, pensions, and other postretirement benefits.

105. The Board believes that the pro forma disclosures required by this Statement will mitigate to some extent the disadvantages of permitting disclosure in lieu of recognition. To disclose only additional details about options granted, vested, forfeited, exercised, expired, and the like would permit only the most sophisticated users of financial statements to estimate the income statement impact of recognizing all compensation costs. Many individual investors and other users of financial statements could not, and even the more sophisticated users would have available less information than the entity itself has on which to base estimates of value and related compensation cost related to employee stock options. The Board's continuing belief that disclosure is not an adequate substitute for recognition of items that qualify for recognition in financial statements is the reason for this Statement's establishment of the fair value based accounting method as preferable for purposes of justifying an accounting change and for encouraging entities to adopt it.

106. The Board did not specifically address during its formal deliberations whether pro forma disclosures of the effects on net income and earnings per share of applying the fair value based method should be included in summarized interim financial data required by APB Opinion No. 28, Interim Financial Reporting. That question arose late in the process of drafting this Statement when some Board members noted that comparable information about earnings and earnings per share presented on a quarterly basis would be important to financial analysis. Other Board members agreed but thought that it was too late in this extraordinarily controversial project to add a requirement for pro forma disclosures in summarized interim financial data. Therefore, this Statement does not require those disclosures. If a need for pro forma disclosures on a quarterly basis becomes apparent, the Board will consider at a later date whether to require those disclosures.

The Value of Employee Stock Options Can Be Estimated within Acceptable Limits for Recognition in Financial Statements

107. The value of employee services rendered is almost always impossible to measure directly. For that reason, accounting for the cost of employee services is based on the value of compensation paid, which is presumed to be an adequate measure of the value of the services received. Compensation cost resulting from employee stock options is measured based on the value of stock options granted rather than on the value of the services rendered by the employee, which is consistent with the accounting for other forms of employee compensation.

108. Trading of options in the financial markets has increased significantly in the last 20 years. During that time, mathematical models to estimate the fair value of options have been developed to meet the needs of investors. Some employers and compensation consultants have used variations of those models in considering how much of a compensation package should consist of employee stock options and in determining the total value of a compensation package that includes stock options. Many that have been using option-pricing models for those purposes said that the existing models are not sufficiently accurate for accounting purposes, although they are adequate for comparing the value of compensation packages across entities and for estimating the value of options in designing compensation packages. Those respondents generally said that a more precise measure is needed for measuring compensation cost in the income statement than for comparing the value of total compensation, including options, paid by various entities or in determining how many options to grant an employee.

109. The Board disagrees with the distinction made by those respondents. One important use of financial statements is to compare the relative attractiveness of investment and lending opportunities available in different entities. Therefore, increasing the comparability of financial statements is a worthy goal, even if all entities use a measurement method that is less precise than the Board or its constituents might prefer.

110. The derivative markets have developed rapidly with the introduction of new kinds of options and option-like instruments, many of which are long term and nontraded--or even nontransferable. For example, interest rate caps and floors, both of which are forms of options, are now common. Often, option components are embedded in other instruments, and both the seller and the purchaser of the instrument need to evaluate the value added by each component of a compound instrument. Mathematical models that extend or adapt traditional option-pricing models to take into account new features of options and other derivative securities also continue to be developed. Sometimes decisions have been made based on inadequate analysis or incomplete models, resulting in large and highly publicized losses for one party to a contract. Those instances usually lead to additional analysis of the instruments in question and further refinement of the models. However, market participants--whether they consider themselves to be traders, investors, or hedgers--continue to commit billions of dollars to positions in options and other derivatives, based at least in part on analysis using mathematical pricing models that are not perfect.

111. The Exposure Draft noted that uncertainties inherent in estimates of the fair value of employee stock options are generally no more significant than the uncertainties inherent in measurements of, for example, loan loss reserves, valuation allowances for deferred tax assets, and pension and other postretirement benefit obligations. All estimates, because they are estimates, are imprecise. Few accrual-based accounting measurements can claim absolute reliability, but most parties agree that financial statement recognition of estimated amounts that are approximately right is preferable to the alternative--recognizing nothing--which is what Opinion 25 accounting recognizes for most employee stock options. Zero is not within the range of reasonable estimates of the value of employee stock options at the date they are granted, the date they vest, or at other dates before they expire, with the possible exception of deep-out-of-the-money options that are near expiration. Even those latter options generally have a nominal value until very shortly before expiration.

112. Many respondents said that the Exposure Draft inappropriately compared the imprecision in estimating the value of employee stock options with similar imprecisions inherent in estimating, for example, the amount of an entity's obligation to provide postretirement health care benefits. They said that because postretirement health care benefits eventually result in cash payments by the entity, the total obligation and related cost are "trued up" over the entity's life. In contrast, the value of employee stock options estimated at the grant date is not trued up to reflect the actual gain, if any, that an employee realizes from an award of employee stock options. Those respondents asserted that the lack of true-up makes it necessary for the estimated value of employee stock options that forms the basis for recognizing the related compensation cost to be more precise than an estimate of the value of the same entity's obligation for postretirement health care benefits.

113. The Board questions that perceived distinction between the relative importance of the precision of estimates of the value of employee stock options and the precision of other estimates inherent in financial statements. Although the total amount of any expense that is ultimately paid in cash will necessarily equal the total of the amounts attributed to each of a series of years, the appropriate amount to attribute to any individual year is never trued up. Nor can the precision of the reported total obligation be determined at any date while it is being incurred. For example, the total cost of a postretirement health care plan will be trued up only if the plan is terminated. Investors, creditors, and other users of financial statements must make decisions based on a series of individual years' financial statements that covers less than the entire life of the entity. For costs such as postretirement health care benefits, the true-up period for an individual employee (or group of similar employees) may be decades, and even then the total amount cannot be separated from amounts attributed to other employees. Concern about the reliability of estimates of the value of employee stock options and the related cost seem equally applicable to annual estimates of, for example, obligations for postretirement benefits and the related cost.

114. The respondents that emphasized the importance of truing up the total cost of a stock-based employee compensation award generally were adamantly opposed to exercise date accounting--the only accounting method for employee stock options that would true up interim cost estimates to equal the total gain, if any, an employee realizes. The Board rejected exercise date accounting for conceptual reasons, as discussed in paragraph 149. However, deferring final measurement of a transaction until enough of the related uncertainties have been resolved to make reasonably reliable measurement possible is the usual accounting response to measurement difficulties for virtually all other transactions except an award to an employee of fixed stock options.

115. The standard Black-Scholes and binomial option-pricing models were designed to estimate the value of transferable stock options. The value of transferable stock options is more than the value of employee stock options at the date they are granted primarily for two reasons. First, transferable stock options can be sold, while employee stock options are not transferable and can only be exercised. Second, an employee can neither sell nor exercise nonvested options. Nonvested employee options cannot be exercised because the employee has not yet fully paid for them and is not obligated to do so. Options other than employee options rarely include a lengthy period during which the holder may choose to walk away from the right to the options.

116. The measurement method in this Statement reduces the estimated value of employee stock options below that produced by an option-pricing model for nonforfeitable, transferable options. Under the method in this Statement, the recognized value of an employee stock option that does not vest--and thus is never issued to the employee--is zero. In addition, the estimated value of an employee stock option is based on its expected life rather than its maximum term, which may be considerably longer. Paragraphs 155-173 explain why the Board believes those adjustments are appropriate and sufficient to deal with the forfeitability and nontransferability of employee stock options.

117. The Board continues to believe that use of option-pricing models, as modified in this Statement, will produce estimates of the fair value of stock options that are sufficiently reliable to justify recognition in financial statements. Imprecision in those estimates does not justify failure to recognize compensation cost stemming from employee stock options. That belief underlies the Board's encouragement to entities to adopt the fair value based method of recognizing stock-based employee compensation cost in their financial statements.

.

 

 

 


Part B (10 Points)
In your own words, briefly summarize in less than 400 words, the arguments against the FASB conclusions in Paragraph 74 of FAS 123.

The major argument against booking of ESOs is that the firm itself never sacrifices assets for value received by employees holding ESOs, including intrinsic value of the options at the time they are exercised.  Assets given up ultimately route to the existing shareholders in the form of dilution of their shares in the assets as is illustrated in Appendix A and B at http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm 

The second major argument is that a new requirement to book ESOs when they vest would add heavily to the burden of having to fully expense R&D expenses under FAS 2.  Many firms, especially high technology firms, are thrown into reporting of net losses for R&D even though R&D expenditures generally have future benefits.  Booking ESOs at fair value would further lower reported earnings, creating enormous reported losses for many firms and raising their cost of capital.

The FASB lists the major arguments in Appendix A of FAS 123 and then counters these arguments.

Excerpts from FAS 123 Appendix A
BASIS FOR CONCLUSIONS

83. Some opponents of recognizing compensation cost for stock options acknowledge that stock options are recognizable compensation, but they say that a requirement to recognize that compensation would have adverse economic consequences because many entities would reduce or eliminate their stock option programs. However, some of the same respondents also said that Opinion 25's bias in favor of fixed awards at the expense of awards with performance conditions, options with indexed exercise prices, and the like should be eliminated because that bias has undesirable economic consequences. It deters employers from using more performance-based awards, which those respondents consider preferable to fixed options in many situations.

84. The Board's operating precepts require it to consider issues in an even-handed manner, without intentionally attempting to encourage or to discourage specific economic actions. That does not imply that improved financial reporting should not have economic consequences; a change in accounting standards that makes available more relevant and representationally faithful financial information often will have economic consequences. For example, the availability of the new information resulting from application of this Statement may lead an entity to reassess the costs and benefits of its existing stock option plans. If a reassessment reveals that the expected benefits of a stock option plan do not justify its costs, a rational response would be to revise or eliminate the plan. However, an entity presumably would not restrict or eliminate a stock option program whose motivational effect on employees is expected to make a net contribution to reported results of operations. To do so would not be rational because continuing the plan would be expected to increase revenues (or to decrease other expenses) more than enough to offset the reported compensation cost. In addition, many small, emerging entities told the Board that stock options often substitute for higher cash wages or other benefits, such as pensions. Significantly reducing those option programs would not make economic sense if employees would demand equal or greater cash wages or other benefits to replace the lost stock options.

85. Some people told the Board that a requirement to recognize compensation cost might bring additional discipline to the use of employee stock options. Unless and until the stock price rises sufficiently to result in a dilutive effect on earnings per share, the current accounting for most fixed stock options treats them as though they were a "free good." Stock options have value--employee stock options are granted as consideration for services and thus are not free.

 

88. Some respondents pointed out that the definition of expenses in FASB Concepts Statement No. 6, Elements of Financial Statements, says that expenses result from outflows or using up of assets or incurring of liabilities (or both). They asserted that because the issuance of stock options does not result in the incurrence of a liability, no expense should be recognized. The Board agrees that employee stock options are not a liability--like stock purchase warrants, employee stock options are equity instruments of the issuer. However, equity instruments, including employee stock options, are valuable financial instruments and thus are issued for valuable consideration, which often is cash or other financial instruments but for employee stock options is employee services. Using in the entity's operations the benefits embodied in the asset received results in an expense, regardless of whether the consideration is cash or other financial instruments, goods, or services. \14/ Moreover, even if shares of stock or other equity instruments are donated to a charity, the fair value of the instruments issued is recognized together with other charitable contributions in determining the issuer's net income. The Board recently reaffirmed that general principle in FASB Statement No. 116, Accounting for Contributions Received and Contributions Made.

===========================================================================
\14/ Concepts Statement 6, paragraph 81, footnote 43, notes that, in concept, most expenses decrease assets. However, if receipt of an asset, such as services, and its use occur virtually simultaneously, the asset often is not recorded. ===========================================================================

96. An equity instrument may be conditionally transferred to another party under an agreement that allows that party to choose at a later date whether to deliver the agreed consideration for it, which may be goods or services rather than cash or financial instruments, or to forfeit the right to the instrument conditionally transferred, with no further obligation. In that situation, the equity instrument is not issued for accounting purposes until the issuing entity has received consideration for it and the condition is thus satisfied. The grant of an employee stock option subject to vesting conditions is an example of such a conditional transfer. For that reason, this Statement does not use the term issued to refer to the grant of a stock option or other equity instrument that is subject to service or performance conditions for vesting. The Board's conclusion that the entity receives no asset at the date employee stock options are granted is consistent with that use of the term issued. That conclusion about the issuance date of employee stock options, in turn, has implications for the appropriate date at which to measure the value of the equity instruments issued. This Statement requires a measurement method that combines attributes of both grant date and vesting date measurement. The Board's conclusions on measurement date and method are discussed in paragraphs 149-154

 

 

 

Some of the major arguments against booking ESOs are given by Walter Schuetz at at http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/schuetze01.htm

His main argument reads as follows:

 

 

 

Excerpts From Accounting for Stock Options Issued to Employees
Walter P. Schuetze   8940 Fair Oaks Pkwy   Boerne, TX 78015 USA
Phone: 210-698-0968   Email: schuetzewalterp@aol.com

At the hearing of the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs on Tuesday, February 26, 2002, in response to your question, I said that, for technical accounting reasons, I would not charge expense for stock options issued to employees.  I said that I would explain why.

 

First, I will define a term.  The word “expense” means (1) a decline in the value of an owned asset, as for example when an account receivable, which was thought to be collectible, goes bad, or (2) the using up of an owned asset, as for example, using cash to pay for advertising.  (Technically, an expense arises when an obligation to transfer assets (to use up assets) arises, for example, on the receipt of goods or services where payment of cash in satisfaction of the obligation is delayed in accordance with normal business terms.)

 

The Financial Accounting Standards Board, in one of its Concepts Statements, defines assets as “…probable future economic benefits obtained or controlled by a particular entity as a result of past transactions or events.”  (That definition is followed by six paragraphs of more than 600 words explaining the definition.)  The International Accounting Standards Board’s definition of assets is similar to the FASB’s in that it is based on “economic benefits.”  Under that definition of assets, the receipt of services from employees is an economic benefit, and the using up of that economic benefit is an expense.  (For FASB mavens, see paragraphs 25—31 of Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 6, “Elements of Financial Statements,” especially paragraph 31, and paragraph 88 of Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 123, “Accounting for Stock-Based Compensation.”)  The value of that economic benefit is hard if not impossible to measure directly, so it is measured indirectly by reference to the cash paid to the employee by the employer, state and Federal taxes paid by the employer on account of the employee/employer relationship, and the cost of medical insurance, maternity leave, child care, vacation, sick leave, and other benefits furnished to the employee by the employer.

 

Defining assets as probable future economic benefits, as the FASB does, results in an expense on the receipt and use of services from employees in exchange for stock or stock options.  The value of the economic benefit received is measured indirectly by reference to the fair value of the stock or stock options issued to the employees.  If, as is generally the case, the stock is restricted stock or if restricted options are issued, the measurement of the fair value of the stock or the options generally is done by formula because reference cannot be made to a market price of the stock or option.

 

So, if you like the FASB’s definition of assets, that is, economic benefits, you get an expense when stock or stock options are issued to employees as the FASB recommended in its Statement 123 issued in 1995 unless you think that it results in “double counting,” which I will explain later on. 

 

I do not like the FASB’s and IASB’s definition of assets; “economic benefits” is too ambiguous, amorphous, and indeterminate.  It is not workable.  Only FASB and IASB accountants know what the term “economic benefits” means, but they cannot explain the term in words that ordinary folk and investors and creditors understand.  When I was on staff at the Securities and Exchange Commission as Chief Accountant and as Chief Accountant of the Commission’s Division of Enforcement, I found “economic benefits” to be so pliable that almost any expenditure, cost, or debit can be said to qualify as an asset, or at least so it is asserted by registrants and their auditors, lawyers, and expert witnesses when challenged by the Commission’s staff or the Commission itself, either informally or in court.  (For proof, I can show you the court filings by respondents and their very distinguished expert witnesses.)  Moreover, using that definition of assets allows junk—rusty junk--to get onto corporate balance sheets—junk that cannot be sold to anyone and therefore has no market value whatsoever—for example, goodwill, deferred income taxes, income tax benefits of operating loss carryforwards, development costs, direct-response advertising costs, debt issue costs, and capitalized interest cost said to relate to the acquisition of fixed assets.  The FASB and IASB say that junk has probable future economic benefits.  I say nonsense.  That junk does not and cannot earn a penny.  When it comes time to pay bills or make contributions to employees’ pension plans, that junk is worthless.  Showing that junk as assets on corporate balance sheets misleads investors.  Showing that junk as assets allows stock prices to soar when the corporate balance sheet is bloated with hot air.

 

In my accounting model, which I have recommended to the FASB and IASB, I define assets as follows:  CASH, claims to CASH (for example, accounts and notes receivable), and things that can be sold for CASH (for example, securities, inventory, trucks, buildings, oil and gas reserves, and patents).  Ordinary folk and investors and creditors understand my definition of assets.  Nothing ambiguous about it.  There are no rusty junk assets on balance sheets prepared using my definition of assets.  And, when assets, as I define assets (and liabilities, as I define liabilities), are shown on corporate balance sheets at their market prices as I have recommended to the FASB and IASB, the balance sheet presents the corporation’s true economic financial condition, not financial position that is determined by reference to the FASB’s mountain of rules and formulas for computing or determining asset and liability amounts, the result of which is not understandable by investors, creditors, and other users of financial statements. 

 

In my accounting, I do not get an expense for the issuance of stock options (or stock for that matter) to employees in return for their services.  No asset, as I define assets, is used up and no asset, as I define assets, declines in value as the result of the issuance of a stock option—thus, no expense

 Continued at http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/schuetze01.htm

 

Bob Jensen’s counter arguments are provided http://www.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Especially note Appendix B of the above document
.

 


Parts 2 and 3 solutions are provided in a separate handout.